Works matching IS 0309166X AND DT 1988 AND VI 12 AND IP 1
1
- Cambridge Journal of Economics, 1988, v. 12, n. 1, p. 55, doi. 10.1093/oxfordjournals.cje.a035049
- Article
2
- Cambridge Journal of Economics, 1988, v. 12, n. 1, p. 97, doi. 10.1093/oxfordjournals.cje.a035053
- Article
3
- Cambridge Journal of Economics, 1988, v. 12, n. 1, p. 95, doi. 10.1093/oxfordjournals.cje.a035052
- Article
4
- Cambridge Journal of Economics, 1988, v. 12, n. 1, p. 125, doi. 10.1093/oxfordjournals.cje.a035041
- Article
5
- Cambridge Journal of Economics, 1988, v. 12, n. 1, p. 67, doi. 10.1093/oxfordjournals.cje.a035050
- Article
6
- Cambridge Journal of Economics, 1988, v. 12, n. 1, p. 179, doi. 10.1093/oxfordjournals.cje.a035045
- Article
7
- Cambridge Journal of Economics, 1988, v. 12, n. 1, p. 169, doi. 10.1093/oxfordjournals.cje.a035044
- Article
8
- Cambridge Journal of Economics, 1988, v. 12, n. 1, p. 135, doi. 10.1093/oxfordjournals.cje.a035042
- Article
9
- Cambridge Journal of Economics, 1988, v. 12, n. 1, p. 43, doi. 10.1093/oxfordjournals.cje.a035048
- Article
10
- Cambridge Journal of Economics, 1988, v. 12, n. 1, p. 37, doi. 10.1093/oxfordjournals.cje.a035047
- Newman, Peter;
- Vassilakis, Spyros
- Article
11
- Cambridge Journal of Economics, 1988, v. 12, n. 1, p. 29, doi. 10.1093/oxfordjournals.cje.a035046
- Article
12
- Cambridge Journal of Economics, 1988, v. 12, n. 1, p. 7, doi. 10.1093/oxfordjournals.cje.a035051
- Article
13
- Cambridge Journal of Economics, 1988, v. 12, n. 1, p. 1, doi. 10.1093/oxfordjournals.cje.a035040
- Article